Author Topic: Long book review: Zoning Rules!  (Read 916 times)

Mark V Anderson

  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 1112
  • Minnesota, US
    • View Profile
Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« on: July 20, 2020, 12:39:35 am »
I wrote this for Scott's book review thing, but of course SSC crashed before it could be published. I am thinking SSC won't come back for a while, so I am putting it here. I hope this isn't too long.

I do hope others with book reviews for Scott's contest will put theirs on DSL also. I was really looking forward to reading all the reviews.



Zoning – friend or foe?

I      Zoning Rules!

I’ve always had a difficult time understanding why the US has a large homeless population and seemingly a large population with outsized housing costs. After all, the free market manages to provide the goods needed to the poor in other areas by simply providing less expensive versions of the goods that the middle class and rich buy. This works for food, clothing, and entertainment. Despite overly-dramatic stories of hungry children in the US, no one in the US is starving, naked, or even missing out on fun and games, absent extraordinary circumstances. So why is it that lots of people can’t find housing for less than 40-50% of their income?

My priors tell me that this has to be because government has artificially increased the price of housing so it is beyond the means of the poorest people. The main culprit in my mind has always been that zoning has caused this problem. But I never understood very well how zoning works in America, so I bought a bunch of books on zoning to educate myself. The best of the books I bought is Zoning Rules!, by William A Fischel.  The author is an economist at Dartmouth College. The book both enhanced and diminished my priors, but certainly increased my knowledge.

Professor Fischel was also on the zoning board in his small town of Hanover, New Hampshire for ten years, chairing it for half of that time. Perhaps being on a town’s zoning board biases him in favor of zoning. But even more importantly, it gave him experience on the ground in how zoning works. He isn’t stuck in the ivory tower just developing theories of how zoning should work, but has worked in the nitty gritty zoning world of a small town. Although he has also created theories of how zoning should work. I think this practical experience greatly enhances the book.

II        Land Use Background

Urban sprawl is in no way going to lead to starvation by decimating cropland. Urban areas took up only 3.2% of land area in the US in 2007. Cropland took 21.5%, forests 36.2%, and grassland 32.3%, so any changes in farmland will likely come from non-urban sources. Strictly speaking, this doesn’t mean urbanizing farmland isn’t a danger, if the particular land being urbanized is particularly good farmland. But it is unlikely that all the best farmland happens to be at the edge of cities.

Cities exist because they increase wealth. Workers in cities are more productive than those outside, and workers in large cities are more productive than workers in smaller cities. The reason city land is so expensive is because density creates wealth. But the densest cities are not the most wealthy. As cities become wealthier, the population uses some of that wealth to create more space for each person. It seems that a certain amount of sprawl is an inherent result of a city becoming rich. The densest cities are in the third world countries of Africa and Asia.

Land is a peculiar type of asset. It is not a thing that one creates and then uses until it wears out or becomes obsolete, such as a machine or a house or a patent. Land is simply a location. It can be improved on with a building or landscaping. Its value may increase or decrease based on its location, but the change in value is rarely the doing of the land owner. One could also argue that ownership of land falls squarely under the Proudhon slogan of “property is theft!,” since if you go far enough back in the ownership chain you find someone who just appropriated the land. No one created it. This last point is all me; Fischel never mentions Proudhon.

This leads to the theory of the land tax, as advocated by the adherents of the economist Henry George. Strict Georgists believe that all land belongs to the community, and so the “tax” on the land should be equivalent to the full land rental value. But even if you don’t go that far, a tax on land makes more sense than on other property since the value of the land has little to do with actions of its owners, and ownership itself is somewhat fraught. When land value quickly increases or decreases, it is usually because of activity that occurs in the area, and not because of actions of the land owners. It has been claimed that any such value increase should thus not belong to the land owners but to the community (for example, see the book Rethinking the Economics of Land and Housing).  Land taxes are also more “efficient” than other taxes, since the owner cannot pass them on to others. A tax on other property may result in less maintenance of the existing asset and creation of fewer of those assets. But a tax on land won’t result in less land. Note that if there is a building on the land, a land tax only taxes the value of the land itself, so it doesn’t matter if the building is a palace or a dump; the land tax will stay the same.

The biggest problem of a land tax is its administration. How do assessors break out the value of a parcel of land from whatever improvements are made on that land? The gold standard for determining the value of any real estate is through an arm’s length sale of the property in a free market. The value is whatever someone is willing to pay for it. But land is rarely sold separately from its improvements, so it is very difficult to determine the true value of the land. Despite these issues, Fischel states there have been studies of cases of separate land tax that indicate it does encourage investment. In Pennsylvania it has been relatively common to have a higher tax rate for the land portion of the real estate than the building. But Fischel says it is becoming less common recently, presumably because of the administrative difficulties.


III     Zoning Background

Land use planning in the US is commonly called “Euclidian zoning.” This is not because of some geometric methodology of zoning, but because of the seminal SCOTUS case on zoning in 1926, Euclid vs Ambler. Euclid is a suburb of Cleveland. The town wanted to divide its land area into regions, and distribute various residential uses (single family homes, apartments) and industrial usage within these regions, as well as provide other rules on area, dimension, and alignment of buildings. Euclid won the case, and most other communities in the US adopted similar rules over the next 10-20 years.

Zoning doesn’t allow personal differentiation of usage (say giving Mr Smith rights that Ms Adams doesn’t have), but does allow to differentiate usage by region. Zoning does allow grandfathering of buildings that were in place when the zoning rules were enacted, which will tend to favor older residents over newer ones. Zoning also allows zoning boards to give variances in certain cases, which gives more power to the politically powerful, and may encourage corruption.

Fischel talks about two cities that are on opposite sides of the zoning continuum. One side is Houston, which has no zoning rules at all. Fischel states that this has resulted in lower housing prices in Houston. He is surprised that Houston voters has consistently voted against zoning (6 referendums), since home owners presumably dominate voting in Houston as everywhere else, and home owners want the value of the homes to increase. Houston does have some land use rules, such as off-parking requirements and historic preservation districts, but not the full spectrum of Euclidean zoning of other cities. Houston also has many private covenants that mimic zoning for small areas. The industrial areas in Houston are separate from residential areas despite the lack of zoning.

Fischel wonders why Houston’s voters have rejected zoning so many times. One of his theories is it because the city of Houston is so large geographically – it continues to annex new areas around it. Individual sections of Houston might have agreed to zoning in the past, to keep out the parts of the metropolitan area they don’t want in their area, but as part of a very large city they don’t want the government to have this power. Of course now Houstonites are aware of their singularity of being the “no-zoning” city, and may be against it just for city pride.

The other side of the continuum is Portland, Oregon. Portland Metro can set zoning for the entire metropolitan area, and the area outside the metro is zoned agricultural by Oregon, so development is not allowed there either. Therefore the usual developer scheme of leap frogging over zoning rules into areas outside those rules don’t work in Portland (although Fischel never mentioned that Portland is on the border with Washington, so why don’t developers leapfrog there?). This apparently has held back some growth in Portland. Portland’s housing prices are above average for a region of its size. Land prices just outside the Metro (where no development is allowed) are dramatically lower than inside the Metro.

Several national laws have complicated the zoning laws in the US.

1)   National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA), the Clean Water Act, and the Endangered Species Act all give activists veto power over development in some cases.

2)   Wetland requirements may allow additional vetoes.


3)   Flood insurance regulations require local zoning rules in some cases.

4)   Fair Housing Act and Americans with Disabilities Act.


5)   Also local laws such as historic districts may also allow veto power over development.

These and other laws often give those opposed to development a double-veto power. Even if the zoning rules don’t stop the development, often these other laws will.

Alternatives to zoning include nuisance laws and private covenants. Presumably before zoning became popular, if say a rendering plant was planning to move next door to your house, you used the nuisance laws to keep them away. Private covenants work well for brand new developments where each new resident has to sign a contract before they move in. However for older communities private covenants don’t work as well because it only takes one nay-sayer to nullify the rules. It is hard to know how well nuisance laws worked before zoning existed. Urbanization was much lower 100 years ago, so it probably isn’t equivalent to today’s world anyway.

Zoning that is explicitly racist was deemed illegal by SCOTUS in 1917. This was even before Euclid, but Euclid did not reverse that piece of zoning law. This was based on the 14th Amendment, seemingly because the law preventing Whites to sell to Blacks interfered with Blacks’ right to own property? Even private covenants to restrict by race were deemed illegal by SCOTUS in 1948.

Fischel has various theories about why zoning became very popular in the ‘20’s and ‘30’s, and then even more restrictive in the ‘70’s.

1)   The rise of the cargo truck in the ‘20’s made it much easier for industry to invade the area of residences. Before trucks were widely available, heavy industry needed to be close to railroad spurs to have access to supplies. Once trucks became ubiquitous, industry could be anywhere there was a road. Therefore, residents could not escape industry simply by moving away from the railroad. Secondly, buses made it easier for apartment dwellers to live in the areas previously inhabited by only single family housing.

2)   The ‘70’s brought very high inflation, including housing inflation. Suddenly one’s house was a very important asset for the future, and maintaining the value of the house became imperative. Municipal zoning to keep out bad influences was seen as the way to do this.


Fischel also talked about why zoning has become above all about protecting the value of single family houses.

a)   Increasing home ownership in the US means a lot more people are interested in home values. https://dqydj.com/historical-homeownership-rate-in-the-united-states-1890-present/

b)   A residence is quite often the largest investment individuals own, so the financial risk is that much greater.


c)   In the 1920’s, transportation options gave many people the ability to live far from where they worked. Therefore, they voted where they lived, but not in the municipality where they worked. Furthermore, it was more beneficial to keep out the annoyance of industry and lower class workers from one’s own residence when you didn’t have to live close to work.


IV    Normative discussion

Fischel thinks that zoning and the real estate property tax is overall a net good. The theory is that if zoning and the tax results in a reasonable weighing of development costs and benefits to the community, then that is a good thing. He is in favor of what he calls “good housekeeping” zoning, which keeps incompatible uses separate. This is something like a loud scrap metal operation being incompatible with nearby residences. What he thinks have gone too far are the broad based growth control zoning laws, which keeps almost all development out of municipalities.

Zoning increases home values by making homes in the area more pleasant to live. This works under the “good housekeeping” model of zoning. However, the anti-growth model of zoning has become more prevalent in the US, especially in California and Northeast, which greatly restricts new development, both industry and residences. This increases home values even more than the good housekeeping model because it restricts the supply of housing. However, while the housing stock becomes more valuable, the undeveloped land becomes less valuable, so the aggregate value of the land is lower than under good housekeeping. Fischel believes the good housekeeping model will maximize the land value in any given municipality, and he implicitly believes this is the best result. He includes a nice graph that illustrates good housekeeping rules creating the greatest aggregate value (pg 325), but he doesn’t provide any evidence that this is true.

Fischel claims that property tax without zoning doesn’t work very well. His example was less than convincing. He gave an example pre-zoning where rich people could simply avoid high property taxes by moving elsewhere, and selling their houses to developers that would build lesser valued apartments, which harmed the city. Whereas with a zoning law, the city could disallow the building of apartments and thus avoid the decrease in tax. The first problem with this case is if the apartments were a lower value than the single family house, why would the developer do this in the first place? The second issue is even if this did work economically, it appears that zoning results in more single family housing and fewer apartments than makes sense economically. This may help the city with its revenue issues, but adds the society-wide problem of not providing enough lower income housing.

Fischel states that the benefit of zoning is that it “makes for more efficient provision of local services and better neighborhoods.” I think part of this is that it makes it more difficult for residents to shop for cheaper property taxes by moving to new communities by making them less able to sell off their properties for development when they leave. But also because it is similar to private covenants in that potential property owners can move into communities that have the kinds of rules they desire. Theoretically homeowners can pick the laws they want to live by. I am not sure if this is really a thing in the US, but it makes good sense in theory.

A major disadvantage of zoning that Fischel highlights is that increases in housing prices make it more difficult for Americans to re-locate to new areas of opportunity when they can’t afford to live there. This is especially the case in California and the Northeast, because of their stratospheric prices.

There have been studies that show that high prices in California and the Northeast are largely due to land use policies in those areas. A study by Gamong and Shoag showed that land use litigation in those two areas increased around 1970, about the same time that housing prices began to shoot upwards. I am not convinced by this study, since a lot of things changed in America around 1970, so such causation is far from definitive.

Fischel says that up until 1970 or so, different towns had different appetites for development, so if a developer was shut out of one place, he could just go to another town. Anti-development citizens in towns where the majority were pro-development couldn’t do much about it. But around 1970 exclusionary zoning became more uniform and stronger in the suburbs (to keep out both industrial and housing projects). He broke down the reasons for this as being supply side and demand side.

I.   Demand (house owners):

1)   Growing suburbanization of employment (industrial parks), which brought more of the lower class to the suburbs,

2)   expansion of egalitarian principles, which in a backlash resulted in “neutral” policies banning all new development (growth management),


3)   sudden growth of housing values, which upped the stakes,

II.   Supply (people who facilitate home ownership, but also outside activists):

4)   expansion of legal standing to opponents of development,

5)   federalization of the environmental movement,

6)   state legislation that established multi-layered review of many projects, so developers had to get approval from both municipal and regional authorities (double veto).

Fischel also thinks interstate highways, built largely in the ‘60’s and ‘70’s, were instrumental pushing many citizens into an anti-growth mode. These highways tore up neighborhoods and separated them from adjoining neighborhoods. Also the highways made the suburbs all the more accessible, and it was the suburbs that had the strongest zoning advocacy.

It is Fischel’s contention that these increased zoning rules greatly drove up house prices starting in the ‘70’s, especially on the West and East Coasts. But why these areas have more restrictive zoning than the inland areas is not easy to answer. Fischel references a couple of experts who believe either high employment diversity or education and quality of life in certain areas drive more zoning. He suggests that high tech in the West and financial services in the East may be responsible, but he is unsure. I am even less sure than he is by this explanation.

Fischel explains the high control of zoning in the Northeast as due to smaller, home-voter controlled governments there, especially the town hall governments in New England. California has larger governments, but initiative/referendum gives more power to voters. The voters focus more on home values, while the bureaucrats work more closely with developers and accept growth more easily. So more voting power leads to stricter zoning.

V      Segue

As impressed as I was with this book, I did find some blind spots. Fischel mostly talked about lot size and restrictions on industry and multi-family housing. These issues are very important in discussing the constraints zoning places on all of us, but zoning is much bigger than that.

For example, he didn’t talk at all about who can live in a home. In Minneapolis, we have rules about unrelated persons living in a household. No more than 3 unrelated people can live in one household in three types of residential zoning, and no more than 5 unrelateds can live in a household in three other types. I suspect that in college I often lived in illegal households, since I often had many housemates, none of whom were related to me. I could never afford to live in my own apartment until I got my first professional job. Quite often it seems to me that affordable housing advocates complain about the rents for efficiencies or one bedroom apartments for the poor. But my belief is that when you are poor, you probably need to have roommates to afford housing. If you are looking for a place by yourself, you are living beyond your means. And it seems the zoning rules make it more difficult for the poor to live with roommates.

Another zoning issue is the constraints most zoning has on boarders in houses. I can’t find such a rule in Minneapolis’ very complex zoning statutes, but I know it is a rule in many cities that they can’t take in boarders to fill up an unused room. Renting as a boarder is another way for the poor to live relatively cheaply, but zoning laws make it difficult for the poor to find places to live.

The complexity of zoning laws themselves increases the cost of housing. I spent hours looking through Minneapolis’s laws, and I was only scanning them. I was wondering if this is only big cities with these extensive laws, so I looked at Richfield, a suburb of Minneapolis where my son lives (with three unrelated housemates by the way). It isn’t short – it would take hours to go through it. So not just big cities.

https://library.municode.com/mn/richfield/codes/code_of_ordinances?nodeId=APXBRIZOCO_S507PUDE_507.07DE

The hours I spent on Minneapolis laws gave me only a very low level understanding of how these laws work. Developers need to hire experts in the particular city’s zoning laws before they lower a spade into the ground, or even buy any property. If you are householder you may need to spend thousands to understand what changes you allowed to do. Or more likely, you will just make changes and hope the city doesn’t notice. Complex zoning laws separate citizens from their government.

One more issue that I suspect makes low income housing more difficult is all the construction methods and lot configuration rules. I don’t know enough about housing construction to make any judgments about the laws I read for Minneapolis, except to state that there are lots and lots of these rules. But my guess is that the requirements are written for middle class and upper class housing, and that it results in lower priced housing costing more than the buyers would pay absent zoning.


VI   Remedies

Fischel lists three different problems with modern zoning regulations:

i)   It segregates the population by income and class and race,

ii)   It causes metropolitan areas to be  more spread out than is efficient, causing too much commuting, housing consumption, and air pollution, and


iii)   It inhibits American economic growth and equality by retarding the migration of people to high-productivity urban areas (this last is referring to the very high housing prices on the East and West coasts).

Interestingly none of these points are what I think to be the biggest problem of zoning: that it makes it very hard to find inexpensive housing. Lots of people are forced to buy more housing than they want. He talks about the extreme example in #3, but even there he is concerned more about the economic potential that is lost, and not the utility lost by the average person spending too much on a house or apartment. Nevertheless, many of the fixes he suggests do coincide with fixes for the problems I see. 

When Fischel finally gets to the point of discussing remedies for the excessive use of zoning, most the discussion relates to changes in the legal landscape. One of the possible fixes is to bring back from the dead nuisance laws that in the old days were the fix when a large smelly industry set up shop next to a residential area. Before zoning existed, this was maybe the only legal way to keep incompatible land uses from being adjacent to each other. But the nuisance laws only kept out the most egregious of uses from residents; it did not work to keep all industry away from residences, or single family housing separate from apartments, both of which were strong inducements for voters to embrace zoning.

But the most common legal fix suggested for over-zoning is beefing up the “takings clauses” of the US Constitution and the state constitutions. When a community passes new zoning laws that restrict the usage of undeveloped land, they reduce the value of that land. This could be treated as “takings,” and subject the community to paying compensation to the owners of undeveloped land. Mostly the courts have not required this. These laws could be made stronger so the courts do take them into account, which would limit the amount of anti-growth zoning communities create.

Fischel pretty much destroys the option of strengthening the “takings clauses” for practical reasons. For one thing, almost all legislation creates winners and losers and thus makes is susceptible to “takings” lawsuits. Where do you draw the line as to what constitutes a compensable taking? The courts currently are pretty conservative in only applying this clause for extreme cases, which is probably the most reasonable approach. Secondly, how do you determine the value of these takings? The value of raw land is very specific to that particular case, so it is very expensive and subject to abuse to determine the reasonable amount in each case. Thirdly it is highly subject to moral hazard, where some developers and speculators would purposefully buy and develop land that they knew would be subject to upcoming legislation. Also owners of land that they mostly considered a nuisance would suddenly decide this land was valuable when anti-development laws were passed.

In my opinion, trying to fix zoning by adding more complex laws is not a good solution.  Changing laws so that developers have more options in court is making the problem worse. Zoning is a major subset of the cost disease. It makes all development a lot more expensive. Developers have to jump a lot more hurdles, often having to pay for reports and development they wouldn’t have done otherwise. Anti-growth zoning also makes development more rare, so developers can charge more when they are done. All this is what makes it more economically reasonable to build luxury housing instead of low income housing.

If the laws were changed to allow developers and landowners to sue under the takings clause or nuisance law, that would mean more time spent in court and more cost added to each project. There would likely be more projects that could be built, but the prices required for these projects would increase once again. I guess it would give lawyers out there more opportunities for employment.  :)  But litigation increases do not add value to the world.  This is also one more complication of government and laws that drives individual property owners and voters further from the government. It drives society away from both the free market and democracy.

However, another way to discourage over-zoning is to make houses less central to their owners. Fischel points out that zoning is mostly demand driven by home owners. This is totally rational behavior, since their houses are a substantial portion of most home-owners net worth. And being immovable assets, their value is greatly affected by events in their locality. Some of the suggestions to lower the value of the houses:

1)   Reduce the mortgage interest deduction. This already has occurred with the latest tax reform that doubled the standard deduction, but could go much further. I think we should eliminate this deduction altogether.

2)   Bring back the tax on gains of house sales. This would make it more like other investments.


3)   Decrease other encouragement of home ownership such as mortgage regulations. It is my understanding that 30 year mortgages would not exist if the government didn’t support them.

4)   Imputed rent on tax returns. That is, the amount of rent the home-owner would pay if someone else owned it would be considered taxable income. This would cause lots of extra work doing taxes, as each home-owner would have to file as if they were a landlord. Fischel says that Switzerland does this; I’d be curious how this works. Another down-side of this is the horizontal equity issues: should everything an individual does for himself be taxable if it is possible to get the service from an outside agency? Such as cooking one’s own meals, cleaning one’s house, even having sex with the other member of the household?  :)


Other suggestions:

5)   Perhaps disallow permanent easements against development in urban areas.

6)   Ease back on the “double-veto” in development. This is where environmental concerns or other issues may deny development even if local zoning allows it. So anti-development activists can go to court using several different rationales. Developers will lose if they don’t win every battle. This also causes a lot of delay, which often costs the developer money, but is free to activists. IMO, this is a major component of the cost disease, but it is hard to know how to fix. Also, because these are generally state-wide or national laws, the Tiebout theory of variety in different communities is defeated.


7)   Low income communities are often more accepting of development, since they place a higher value on more jobs than having a quiet community. State laws should be more flexible in allowing local variation. This is an extension of #6.

8)   Less federal intervention in local zoning issues, such as with environmental laws implying that we are running out of farmland. Let the states decide. I think this is another “double-veto” issue.


9)   Avoid rent control, which decreases rental housing and pushes more people into home ownership. He says this isn’t very common in the US now, but should be avoided for the future.

Lots of people have lots of complicated ideas for fixing zoning. Part of the reasons there are so many fixes is because there are also lots of conflicting goals. Fischel mostly wants to avoid the NIMBYism of anti-growth everywhere. Many want to ensure racial integration and income variation in every community. My goals are to allow the free market to create low income housing and any other types of housing that is demanded, but to hopefully allow small communities to live the way they want.

After reading this book, I don’t think my goals are contradictory. It is the over-arching federal and state and metropolitan area laws that insist that every community within their governing area have a certain grouping of population, with little variation. I think everyone would have a place to live if we let each community decide. We do need some nationwide and statewide environmental laws, since the environment bleeds across all geographic boundaries. I’m not sure how to reconcile such laws with community control. I would like to see various social engineering laws to disappear, such as laws mandating racial, income, etc. laws within each community.

VII   Postscript

I sent an e-mail to Professor Fischel asking him about the other issues in zoning, such as unrelated persons living in a household, taking in boarders, construction methods, and the very complicated laws. I was pleasantly surprised when he responded, and with specific responses to my questions.

Fischel does not believe that these other issues have a significant effect on the amount of low income housing. He believes the anti-growth mindset resulting in large lot sizes and low density have caused most of these problems.

I respect Fischel’s much greater knowledge than me on zoning issues, but I still think zoning causes a shortage of low income housing from more than just the decreased density that it often requires. I did send him a follow-up e-mail suggesting that Houston style lack of zoning had a lot more upsides than downsides (in fact I don’t think he listed any such downsides in his book). Thus far I haven’t received an answer to this second inquiry.


« Last Edit: July 27, 2020, 02:57:32 am by Cassander »
Simplify government today! Or maybe tomorrow

obormot

  • Administrator
  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 2546
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #1 on: July 20, 2020, 12:58:55 am »
Meta: I changed the tags slightly (s/effort/effort post/) for consistency.

BBA

  • Senior Member
  • ****
  • Posts: 279
  • prinny dood!
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #2 on: July 20, 2020, 04:26:17 am »
At least here in New York City, many of the rules driving up the cost of housing are in the state Multiple Dwelling Law and city Housing Maintenance Code rather than the Zoning Resolution. Aside from having been enacted by separate political bodies (the state legislature, city council, and city planning commission respectively) a major difference between these laws is a developer sometimes can get a zoning variance, but there are no variances available to MDL and HMC requirements.

The MDL is the direct successor to the tenement house laws, which date back to the 19th century and were intended to combat the squalid, overcrowded conditions in Manhattan's slums. (Which, as documented by Jacob Riis, were very much a problem.) It has rules on minimum apartment sizes, maximum occupancy limits, and how many unrelated people can share a single housing unit. The HMC is similar but applies to all rental housing, including detached single family homes. Both are uniform laws governing all housing regardless of location, so they would not be considered "zoning" laws.

Now add in the complexity of the Zoning Resolution and the rules around, e.g., air rights transfers, and it's a wonder anything gets built here at all. When I was a child my parents added a floor to our house in the Bronx, and (they tell me) it was very difficult to get approval for the building permits until they hired an "expediter" to push it through the bureaucratic process... I'm not saying bribery was involved, but I'm not saying bribery wasn't involved either.

pete

  • Junior Member
  • **
  • Posts: 78
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #3 on: July 20, 2020, 08:19:26 pm »
One of the things that doesn't come up in these discussions is minimum lot size.  I remember reading a theory a long time ago that the reason for the success of the Massachusetts Bay Colony and the failure of the Plymouth Colony was that the former had laws restricting the subdivision of farm land.  In the Bay Colony only one of the sons (supposedly often the youngest) could inherit the family farm, and the rest had to go out into the world to make their fortune.   Just a few miles south, the family farm could get subdivided into smaller and smaller parcels, and the sons were more likely to stay home.

tg56

  • Junior Member
  • **
  • Posts: 82
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #4 on: July 20, 2020, 10:47:02 pm »
"2)   Bring back the tax on gains of house sales. This would make it more like other investments."

The prolem with this is that it makes it harder to move and right-size housing which has it's own issues (see CA and prop 13). The current approach is really just a band-aid on it, but I'm not sure there are hugely better approaches.  Could tax the capital gains each year (mark to market) or something like that (pros: should reduce the incentive for homeowners to inflate property prices somewhat, cons: taxing people out of their homes [see CA property taxes]). My preference would probably be allowing rolling the basis into the new house (often done for rental properties) e.g. allow 1031 transfers scaled by cost of new property for residences as well.

acymetric

  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 1979
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #5 on: July 20, 2020, 10:50:31 pm »
I can never quite shake the feeling that if we treated houses more like expensive purchases and less like an investment we would be better off, but I suppose it probably isn't possible.

The Nybbler

  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 6507
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #6 on: July 20, 2020, 11:17:19 pm »
I don't see how making home ownership more expensive with all those various tax proposals relates to zoning.  After you've finished taxing us on those mostly-inflationary gains and completely imaginary imputed rent, many of the remaining homeowners still aren't going to want to live next to smelly industry or a loud restaurant.  Renters likely don't want to live in such places either.  So there's still going to be plenty of pressure for zoning. 

Mark V Anderson

  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 1112
  • Minnesota, US
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #7 on: July 20, 2020, 11:24:21 pm »
Quote
One of the things that doesn't come up in these discussions is minimum lot size.

I am confused about this comment, because much of the book and my essay was about density, which is mostly minimum lot sizes.

Quote
At least here in New York City, many of the rules driving up the cost of housing are in the state Multiple Dwelling Law and city Housing Maintenance Code rather than the Zoning Resolution. Aside from having been enacted by separate political bodies (the state legislature, city council, and city planning commission respectively) a major difference between these laws is a developer sometimes can get a zoning variance, but there are no variances available to MDL and HMC requirements.

Yes things just keep getting more complicated. And perhaps that is part of the strategy of policy makers. The more complicated the law is, the harder it is to identify the particular laws that are causing problems. So those policy makers can continue to have political control of what's going on without outsiders able to do anything about it (because few understand it). It sounds like those MDL and HMC requirements have essentially the same effects as zoning (limiting what buildings can go where), so they are really just extensions. And this all is part of the cost disease.
Simplify government today! Or maybe tomorrow

Mark V Anderson

  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 1112
  • Minnesota, US
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #8 on: July 20, 2020, 11:42:22 pm »
I don't see how making home ownership more expensive with all those various tax proposals relates to zoning.  After you've finished taxing us on those mostly-inflationary gains and completely imaginary imputed rent, many of the remaining homeowners still aren't going to want to live next to smelly industry or a loud restaurant.  Renters likely don't want to live in such places either.  So there's still going to be plenty of pressure for zoning. 

The reason for adding more costs (or subtracting benefits) of housing is to drive down the value of owned housing. The main purpose of this is to make owned housing a smaller component of one's net worth so it isn't as salient to homeowners. Yes, everyone has wanted to avoid unpleasant neighbors since forever, and that was a main driver of zoning starting in the '20's. But most zoning controversies these days aren't about keeping noises or smells away from their residences, but to increase the value of one's house as much as possible (citation needed). I think we've all heard that living in a well-to-do neighborhood will greatly increase the value of your house. So everyone tries to prohibit cheaper houses in their neighborhood os they can maximize their house value. To me it appears that every single development proposed is evaluated mostly based on what it will do to housing values. Zoning is rarely about keeping unpleasant neighbors away, unless you define unpleasant as anything that won't increase the value of your house. IMO, zoning has become a monster that greatly impedes freedom of people to live and work where they want. Nuisance laws can take care of unpleasant neighbors without all-emcompassing zoning.

I'd like to hear from Houstonites if they can tell me if the lack of zoning has caused them problems.
Simplify government today! Or maybe tomorrow

The Nybbler

  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 6507
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #9 on: July 21, 2020, 12:02:45 am »
I think the "(citation needed)" says it all.  People don't mostly support zoning laws to raise the financial value of their home; they do it to raise the utility of their home.  Talking about financial value is just away to make that argument legible.

pete

  • Junior Member
  • **
  • Posts: 78
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #10 on: July 21, 2020, 01:48:45 am »
Quote
One of the things that doesn't come up in these discussions is minimum lot size.

I am confused about this comment, because much of the book and my essay was about density, which is mostly minimum lot sizes.

Well then, you can take the history of zoning (at least in North America) back to the 1600's, although I think the land use restrictions are more recent.

Your discussion makes it sound like zoning was invented in 1926.

albatross11

  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 3860
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #11 on: July 21, 2020, 04:50:10 pm »
Mark V Anderson: Thanks for the effort-post/review--this was really nice!

I suspect that the regulatory complexity and opacity of how the rules will be applied, plus the potential for decades of lawsuits to delay things, has a huge impact on development.  Probably a lot of people with good ideas for new development give up when they find that it's almost impossible to determine whether they'll be allowed to do it without a decade of fighting it out with zoning boards, regulators, and the neighbors.  Friction matters. 

ETA:

I also think this probably works in the favor of established developers, who know the unwritten rules, know which palms to grease, have contacts within the government who can help them get favorable rulings, etc. 

It would be interesting to see what would happen if you could establish some very simple zoning rules that were legible to everyone, and that implemented approximately the same set of restrictions as some other places with very complex and opaque zoning rules.  I'd guess the more legible ones would have more growth and innovation, all else equal.  But it would be interesting to find out. 
« Last Edit: July 21, 2020, 04:53:47 pm by albatross11 »
"The universal aptitude for ineptitude makes any human accomplishment an incredible miracle."  (Stapp's Law)

quanticle

  • Moderator Emeritus
  • Serious Time Waster
  • ***
  • Posts: 1463
  • English Muffin Heretic
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #12 on: July 21, 2020, 06:04:31 pm »
Ease back on the “double-veto” in development. This is where environmental concerns or other issues may deny development even if local zoning allows it.

From seeing the effects of development in India, I have some pretty strong qualms about this one. I come from Odisha, and the second largest city in that state is Cuttack. Even though Cuttack is located in a delta, it used to rarely flood because it had a pretty strong system of wetlands around it that would absorb and redirect rainwater. As the city grew, no provision was made for preserving those wetlands, and now even moderate rainfalls lead to waist-deep water in some areas. I've heard similar stories about Delhi and Bangalore as well.

In my opinion, one of the best parts of development policy in Minnesota is our relatively strong bias towards preserving wetlands, and I would be loath to ease back on it without some pretty convincing evidence that other steps (like allowing single-family housing to be converted into multi-family dwellings) had been taken first.

Another thing which I didn't see mentioned at all in the review was traffic. I've been to some city council meetings and one of the main concerns that comes up time and again when people speak about new development is whether the roads can handle the additional traffic. This is especially the case when considering new large multi-family dwellings, like apartment buildings. People think, "Oh god, the road is already having trouble handling the traffic that's on it, and you're thinking of adding another 500-1000 cars at rush hour‽"

albatross11

  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 3860
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #13 on: July 21, 2020, 06:24:17 pm »
I think we need to split out two things:

a. Environmental regulations that we need to avoid, say, destroying some endangered species to make a strip mall.

b. Endless delaying actions that can be carried out to try to choke out some development you don't want for some reason.  (This can be homeowners worried about property values, or activists who oppose all development in some area on principle, or just folks trying to extort some money or other concessions from the developer by becoming an obstacle.).

I'd be very supportive of a reasonably fast one-shot approval/refusal on environmental issues, and also other regulatory issues.  Require it to be completed in 90 days, and make further lawsuits on environmental issues have a big uphill struggle once the environmental approval has happened.  (This would probably need to be extended for rare very large projects--building a strip mall is quite different from building a huge dam, for example.). The goal here is to prevent the situation where some development is delayed for decades by lawsuit after lawsuit. 
"The universal aptitude for ineptitude makes any human accomplishment an incredible miracle."  (Stapp's Law)

radu.floricica

  • Senior Member
  • ****
  • Posts: 381
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #14 on: July 21, 2020, 06:50:24 pm »
First: great post.

Regarding things like occupancy laws, I have a more generic pet peeve with laws that completely miss their mark. I'd make a meta rule that any law that's ignored by the public too long is automatically void. Like speed limits - if 990 cars in a thousand go over the limit in a certain portion of the road, what's the moral justification for giving a fine to a few random drivers one day? It's clearly a problem outside of simply respecting the law - maybe the signs aren't prominent enough, or maybe the limit is just set too low. Or if the problem is just with enforcement - place a cop car there for a few weeks and keep giving fines until you get better numbers.

Occupancy standards are similar. You set a minimum dwelling size, thus you make studios too expensive and you end up with people sharing apartments. Quite the opposite of what you intended - and also making the law quite ignored in practice, since the actual density per building is much higher than theoretically allowed.

I also have an argument pro zoning laws - though it's not really about zoning per se, it's about commons and externalities (yes, I have a thing with commons). In places where zoning laws are lax or easily bribed through, like it's the case here in Romania, you end up with developers building and selling whole neighborhoods without sufficient necessities like parking space. Which then turns into the city/tax payer's problem. That's bad. If you expect to house 300 people that on average own 120 cars, you should have 120 parking spaces somewhere. Otherwise you're just being covertly subsidised (if the city builds parking spaces) or just dump your negative externalities to the whole city.



quanticle

  • Moderator Emeritus
  • Serious Time Waster
  • ***
  • Posts: 1463
  • English Muffin Heretic
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #15 on: July 21, 2020, 09:00:43 pm »
I think we need to split out two things:

a. Environmental regulations that we need to avoid, say, destroying some endangered species to make a strip mall.

b. Endless delaying actions that can be carried out to try to choke out some development you don't want for some reason.

The problem is that, on the ground, (a) and (b) are nigh impossible to distinguish, except in very extreme circumstances. One of the reasons that Mountain View has restricted Google from building additional housing for its workers is over concerns regarding the endangered burrowing owl. Is this a real concern? Or is it a pretext on the part of a bunch of NIMBYs who want to preserve a suburban aesthetic to their town? I know which side I come down on, but I can't tell whether my judgement is an accurate reflection of the participants' motives or whether it's only a reflection of my own biases.

Similarly, here in Minnesota, every time there's new construction, people raise complaints about wetlands being destroyed. I spoke above about how I think that Minnesota's bias for preserving wetlands is a strength, but I'm not going to deny that in certain circumstances, that bias does get exploited to restrict growth.

I'd be very supportive of a reasonably fast one-shot approval/refusal on environmental issues, and also other regulatory issues.

The problem is that assumes that the participants in the process meet certain standards of honesty and competence. The reality is that developers can and will shade the truth in order to get their projects approved, and, depending on current political lean of the executive, the regulatory agencies might be inclined to let them. In this situation, activists use the courts to, in essence, force the executive to enforce rules that it may be otherwise disinclined to.

Again, this mechanism can be used to restrict growth, but it also can be used to force the government to actually review a proposal, rather than just giving it a rubber-stamp approval.

I don't have a lot of good answers. I just wanted to note that all these rules and procedures that we pillory as anti-growth kudzu were the result of years of activism by people who had seen the consequences of unrestricted growth and pollution.

Mark V Anderson

  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 1112
  • Minnesota, US
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #16 on: July 22, 2020, 12:27:23 am »
Quote
I don't have a lot of good answers. I just wanted to note that all these rules and procedures that we pillory as anti-growth kudzu were the result of years of activism by people who had seen the consequences of unrestricted growth and pollution.

Yes I agree that answers are hard to come by. Although I look at it mostly from the other side in that I've never lived in any era of unrestricted growth and pollution (and I'm 64). Mostly I've lived in suffocating restriction on growth and freedom. Your mileage will vary.

But the most important issue is the one that albatross picked up on, which is the complications are the biggest problem. I agree that wetlands are mostly a good thing. I also agree that preserving endangered species is a good thing, and limiting air and water pollution is a good thing, and keeping bad smells and unpleasant noises out of residential neighborhoods is a good thing. All these are good things, but when you have dozens of such restrictions written on thousands of pages of national, state and local laws, after a while you can't do much of anything. Or at least you must spend hundreds of thousands of dollars of legal fees to do developments, and cover the cost of years of delays.

And I think this is inextricably linked to the high cost of housing. Lots of poor people spend a high proportion of their income on housing, and a lot of the reason is all the land use regulations the US has, whether it be zoning, wetlands laws, endangered species laws, or whatever. I am still researching this area, but at this point I'd like to see zoning laws mostly abandoned, and national/state land use laws greatly simplified. Houston seems to do fine with no zoning, and their housing costs are lower than most (and significantly lower than other such enormous cities).
Simplify government today! Or maybe tomorrow

obormot

  • Administrator
  • Serious Time Waster
  • *****
  • Posts: 2546
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #17 on: July 22, 2020, 05:29:51 am »
I think it is worth distinguishing between two things:

The burden (placed upon would-be developers) of going through all the relevant laws, regulations, etc., to confirm that your new development is not in violation of any such things, of filing the requisite paperwork to prove that your new development is not in violation of any such things, and otherwise establishing that you are, by building whatever it is you want to build, not going to do anything that the people of an area have (ostensibly) collectively decided ought not be done.

and

The obstacle (placed in the path of would-be developers) consisting directly of the laws, regulations, etc., that forbid the doing of certain things, or mandate the doing of other things (taken separately from the burden imposed by the enforcement mechanisms of those laws and regulations).

Arguments for the latter are not at all arguments for the former, and leave entirely open the possibility of streamlining the bureaucracy involved in the development process.

Conversely, arguments against the former fail entirely to argue against the latter; having swept aside all paperwork, we may still declare that, actually, upon the most sober consideration of the pros and cons of this specific situation, we do not want your new development to be built (because it would destroy wetlands, or endanger our beloved burrowing owls, or for any other reason).

benschwab

  • Junior Member
  • **
  • Posts: 44
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #18 on: July 22, 2020, 04:45:59 pm »
It is possible that developers actually like having a super complicated regulatory system for development.  The developers with established relationships with those on planing boards and regulatory agencies know how to get variances and speed through reviews and inspections while their would be competitors don't yet have this infrastructure and thus would have trouble getting off the ground.  This would be an iron triangle: the established developers, the members of the local planing board, and the bureaucrats who review potential projects.  If I remember my schooling, the best way to defeat an iron triangle is to have another iron triangle collide with it.  One possibility is low income housing groups, state legislators, and public works agencies or housing authorities.

quanticle

  • Moderator Emeritus
  • Serious Time Waster
  • ***
  • Posts: 1463
  • English Muffin Heretic
    • View Profile
Re: Long book review: Zoning Rules!
« Reply #19 on: July 22, 2020, 05:59:21 pm »
Conversely, arguments against the former fail entirely to argue against the latter; having swept aside all paperwork, we may still declare that, actually, upon the most sober consideration of the pros and cons of this specific situation, we do not want your new development to be built (because it would destroy wetlands, or endanger our beloved burrowing owls, or for any other reason).

The problem, is that, in a sense, the paperwork is the sober consideration you speak of. Like I outlined above, one of the reasons that environmental decisions are so often litigated in the courts is because the executive branch has a long history of abandoning sober consideration and just rubber-stamping projects. As a result, activists resort to lawsuits in order to force the government to undertake the sober consideration of which you speak.

It is possible that developers actually like having a super complicated regulatory system for development.  The developers with established relationships with those on planing boards and regulatory agencies know how to get variances and speed through reviews and inspections while their would be competitors don't yet have this infrastructure and thus would have trouble getting off the ground.

If we look at e.g. San Francisco, nobody is "speeding through reviews". It doesn't matter how established or well-connected a developer is, tearing down a building and redeveloping still takes the better part of a decade, even if they know all the people in the regulatory agencies, the planning boards and have the read the zoning codes cover-to-cover.

In a sense, the sort of corrupt system that you're describing would be better than the current system, because at least someone would be able to get projects through and get things built. In the current system, any random person off the street with a moderate social media presence can organize enough people to get a veto on new development.

PS: Yes I understand I just contradicted myself in my two replies. Deal with it 😎